efek

Jumat, 01 April 2016

aspek hukum

ASPEK HUKUM

1Jelaskan pengertian tujuan dan sumber hukum
     Jawab :
Tujuan hukum menurut pendapat ahli :
1.     Purnadi dan Soejono Soekanto, tujuan hukum adalah kedamaian hidup antar pribadi yang meliputi ketertiban ekstern antar pribadi dan ketenangan intern pribadi.
2.    Van Apeldoorn, tujuan hukum adalah mengatur pergaulan hidup manusia secara damai. Hukum menghendaki perdamaian. Perdamain diantara manusia dipertahankan oleh hukum dengan melindungi kepentingan-kepentingan hukum manusia tertentu, kehormatan, kemerdekaan, jiwa, harta benda terhadap pihak yg merugikan.
3.    R. Soebekti, tujuan hukum adalah bahwa hukum itu mengabdi kepada tujuan negara yaitu mendatangkan kemakmuran dan kebahagiaan para rakyatnya. Hukum melayani tujuan negara tersebut dengan menyelenggarakan “keadilan” dan “ketertiban”.
4.    Aristoteles, hukum mempunyai tugas yang suci yaitu memberi kepada setiap orang yang ia berhak menerimanya. Anggapan ini berdasarkan etika dan berpendapat bahwa hukum bertugas hanya membuat adanya keadilan saja.
5.    SM. Amin, SH tujuan hukum adalah mengadakan ketertiban dalam pergaulan manusia, sehingga keamanan dan ketertiban terpelihara.


Kesimpulan Tujuan Hukum :
1.     Tujuan hukum itu sebenarnya menghendaki adanya keseimbangan kepentingan, ketertiban, keadilan, ketentraman, kebahagiaan,damani sejahtera setiap manusia.
2.    Dengan demikian jelas bahwa yang dikehendaki oleh hukum adalah agar kepentingan setiap orang baik secara individual maupun kelompok tidak diganggu oleh orang atau kelompok lain yang selalu menonjolkan kepentingan pribadinya atau kepentingan kelompoknya.
3.    Inti tujuan hukum adalah agar tercipta  kebenaran dan keadilan
Sumber-sumber hukum :
Pengertian sumber hukum
Sumber hukum adalah segala apa saja (sesuatu) yang menimbulkan aturan-aturan yg mempunyai kekuatan mengikat dan bersifat memaksa, yakni aturan-aturan yang kalau dilanggar mengakibatkan sanksi yang tegas dan nyata bagi pelanggarnya.
Yang dimaksud dengan segala apa saja (sesuatu) yakni faktor-faktor yang berpengaruh terhadap timbulnya hukum, faktor-faktor yang merupakan sumber kekuatan berlakunya hukum secara formal, darimana hukum itu dapat ditemukan. dsb.





2. Klasifikasi dan kaidah – kaidah hukum
    Jawab :
A.     Berdasarkan fungsinya, hukum dapat dibedakan menjadi :
1.   Hukum materiil, Yaitu : segala kaidah yang menjadi patokan manusia dalam bersikap, misalnya tidak boleh membunuh, harus melunasi hutang dan lain sebagainya. Contoh hukum materiil : Kitab Undang-Undang Pidana (KUHP), Kitab Undang-Undang Perdata (KUHPerdata), UU No. 1 Tahun 1974.
2.  Hukum formil (hukum acara),yaitu aturan main penegakkan hukum materiil tersebut. Dengan bahasa lain hukum formil merupakan berisi kaidah-kaidah yang mengatur cara-cara mempertahankan atau cara menjalankan hukum materiil, misalnya dalam mengajukan gugatan seorang penggugat (orang yang menggugat) harus mengajukan surat gugatan ke pengadilan tempat kediaman tergugat (orang yang digugat) sesuai asas actor sequitur forum rei, atau dalam menanggapi surat gugatan penggugat tergugat harus membuat surat jawaban dan lain sebagainya.
Contoh hukum formil : Kitab Undang-Undang Hukum Acara Pidana (KUHAP), Hukum Acara Perdata (dalam HIR), Hukum Acara Tata Usaha Negara, dll.
B.     Berdasarkan isi atau hubungan yang diatur oleh hukum, hukum dapat dibedakan menjadi :
1)    Hukum publik,
2)   Hukum privat (perdata)
Menurut Apeldoorn, hukum publik adalah hukum yang mengatur kepentingan umum, sedangkan hukum privat mengatur kepentingan khusus. Menurut Utrech, anggapam Apeldoorn tidak tepat, sebab baik peraturan hukum publik maupun hukum perdata dapat mengatur suatu kepentingan umum, misalnya apabila pemerintah menyewa sebuah bangunan yang dipergunakan untuk pembangunan rumah sakit umum.
1. Yang termasuk dalam hukum publik, yaitu :
a.   Hukum Pidana
b.   Hukum Tata Negata
c.   Hukum Tata Usaha Negara
d.  Hukum Acara (Pidana, Perdata, Tata Usaha Negara)
e.    Hukum Internasional
2. Yang termasuk dalam hukum privat, yaitu :
a.     Hukum Perdata (BW, Islam, adat)
b.     Hukum dagang
c.      Hukum Perselisihan
d.     Hukum Perdata Internasional

3.jelaskan subyek-subyek hokum (manusia,badan hukum,benda bergerak dan benda tidak bergerak)
Jawab:
Subjek Hukum adalah orang pembawa hak dan kewajiban atau setiap mahkluk yang berwenang untuk memiliki, memperoleh dan menggunakan hak dan kewajiban dalam lalu lintas hukum.
Subjek hukum terdiri dari 2 yaitu :
1. Manusia (naturlife persoon)
Menurut hukum, tiap-tiap seorang manusia sudah menjadi subyek hukum secara kodrati atau secara alami. Anak-anak serta balita pun sudah dianggap sebagai subyek hukum. Manusia dianggap sebagai hak mulai ia dilahirkan sampai dengan ia meninggal dunia. Bahkan bayi yang masih berada dalam kandungan pun bisa dianggap sebagai subyek hukum bila terdapat urusan atau kepentingan yang menghendakinya. Namun, ada beberapa golongan yang oleh hukum dipandang sebagai subyek hukum yang "tidak cakap" hukum. Maka dalam melakukan perbuatan-perbuatan hukum mereka harus diwakili atau dibantu oleh orang lain. seperti:
·        Anak yang masih dibawah umur, belum dewasa, dan belum menikah.
·        Orang yang berada dalam pengampunan yaitu orang yang sakit ingatan, pemabuk, pemboros.

2. Badan Hukum (recht persoon)
Badan hukum adalah suatu badan yang terdiri dari kumpulan orang yang diberi status "persoon" oleh hukum sehingga mempunyai hak dan kewajiban. Badan hukum dapat menjalankan perbuatan hukum sebagai pembawa hak manusia. Seperti melakukan perjanjian, mempunyai kekayaan yang terlepas dari para anggotanya dan sebagainya. Perbedaan badan hukum dengan manusia sebagai pembawa hak adalah badan hukum tidak dapat melakukan perkawinan, tidak dapat diberi hukuman penjara, tetapi badan hukum dimungkinkan dapat dibubarkan.
Objek hukum adalah segala sesuatu yang bermanfaat bagi subjek hukum dan dapat menjadi objek dalam suatu hubungan hukum. Misalkan benda-benda ekonomi, yaitu benda-benda yang untuk dapat diperoleh manusia memerlukan “pengorbanan” dahulu sebelumnya. Hal pengorbanan dan prosedur perolehan benda-benda tersebut inilah yang menjadi sasaran pengaturan hukum dan merupakan perwujudan dari hak dan kewajiban subjek hukum yang bersangkutan sehingga benda-benda ekonomi tersebut menjadi objek hukum. Sebaliknya benda-benda non ekonomi tidak termasuk objek hukum karena untuk memperoleh benda-benda non ekonomi tidak diperlukan pengorbanan mengingat benda-benda tersebut dapat diperoleh secara bebas.
Akibatnya, dalam hal ini tidak ada yang perlu diatur oleh hukum. Karena itulah akan benda-benda non ekonomi tidak termasuk objek hukum. Misalkan sinar matahari, air hujan, hembusan angin, aliran air di daerah pegunungan yang terus mengalir melalui sungai-sungai atau saluran-saluran air.
Bagian-Bagian Objek hukum dapat dibedakan menjadi :
a. Benda Bergerak
Benda bergerak adalah benda yang menurut sifatnya dapat berpindah sendiri ataupun dapat dipindahkan. Benda bergerak dapat dibedakan menjadi dua, yaitu :
Benda Bergerak karena sifatnyameja, kursi, mobil, motor, komputer, dll.
Benda Bergerak karena Ketentuan Undang – Undangsaham, obligasi, cek, tagihan – tagihan, dll.
b. Benda tidak bergerak
Pengertian benda tidak bergerak adalah penyerahan benda tetapi dahulu dilakukan dengan penyerahan secara yuridis. Dalam hal ini untuk menyerahkan suatu benda tidak bergerak dibutuhkan suatu perbuatan hukum lain dalam bentuk akta balik nama. dapat dibedakan menjadi tiga, yaitu :
Benda tidak bergerak karena sifatnya
Tidak dapat berpindah dari satu tempat ke tempat yang lain atau biasa dikenal dengan benda tetap.
contohnya : pohon dan tanah
Benda tidak bergerak karena tujuannya
Tujuan pemakaiannya :
Segala apa yang meskipun tidak secara sungguh – sungguh digabungkan dengan tanah atau bangunan untuk mengikuti tanah atau bangunan itu untuk waktu yang agak lama
contohnya : mesin pabrik
Benda tidak bergerak karena ketentuan undang – undangSegala hak atau penagihan yang mengenai suatu benda yang tak bergerak.
Membedakan benda bergerak dan benda tidak bergerak ini penting, artinya karena berhubungan dengan empat hal adalah pemilikan, penyerahan, daluarsa, dan, pembebanan.












Sumber:



Senin, 30 November 2015

JURNAL 2 (SOFTSKILL EKONOMI KOPERASI)

Banks and Bank Systems, Volume 5, Issue 2, 2010

Cândida Ferreira (Portugal)

The credit channel transmission of monetary policy in the European Union: a panel data approach

Abstract

This paper seeks to contribute to the analysis of the financial integration, the importance of bank performance condi-tions and the bank lending channel transmission of monetary policy in the European Union countries since 1999. Using pooled panel OLS estimations and dynamic Arellano-Bond GMM estimations with quarterly data for 26 EU countries for the period from Q1 1999 to Q3 2006 it confirms the high degree of integration between the EU financial systems, as well as the importance of bank performance conditions to the credit-lending channel of monetary policy in the EU. Furthermore, it demonstrates not only the quite high degree of openness of the financial markets but also their indebt-edness and the dependence of the EU banking institutions on the financial resources of other countries.

Keywords: European integration, bank credit, monetary policy transmission, panel estimates.

JEL Classification: E4, E5, G2.



Introduction ©

The introduction of the single currency has acceler-ated the process of consolidation and financial inte-gration, not only in the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU), but in the whole European Union (EU), in which the new member states also have a voice, in spite of the possible heterogeneous nature of their financial systems.

The process of financial integration is, on the one hand, a necessary pre-requisite for the adoption of the single currency and the implementation of the single monetary policy, with the predominance of the banking intermediation in the context of the EU. On the other hand, this process raises the potential to incite liquidity crises, which could become conta-gious and affect the increasingly integrated Euro-pean financial system.

More efficient credit sectors should contribute to the economic benefits of the other sectors and agents which use financial services and they also represent a necessary condition for the transmission mecha-nism of monetary policy.

According to the credit and lending view, the effec-tiveness of monetary policy depends basically on the banking system, since imperfections, such as asym-metric information and the subsequent phenomena of adverse selection and moral hazard, exist in the capi-tal markets, which increase the particular difficulties felt by some economic agents to finance their invest-ment and consumption plans. Under these conditions, central banks control the supply of money, but the banking institutions also play an important role in the money-creation process, as well as in the mobiliza-tion and allocation of financial resources.

In addition, more efficient banking sectors are gen-erally recognized as a necessary condition for the transmission mechanism of monetary policy and the way that banks adapt lending in response to mone-tary policy decisions varies according to their spe-cific political and economic environment.

However, there is no agreement on the precise specification of the ways in which monetary policy influences the economy. Hence, it is an area merit-ing further investigation (Goddart et al., 2007).

Following these vectors of research, this paper seeks to contribute to the analysis of the financial integra-tion, the importance of bank performance conditions and the bank lending channel transmission of mone-tary policy in the EU countries since 1999.

The main contributions are to be found in:

1.     The use of quarterly data, between Q1 1999 and Q3 2006, for 26 EU1 countries (the only excep-tion is Luxembourg, for which it was not possi-ble to obtain all the data). This is in contrast with most of the empirical studies in this area, which analyze only sub-sets of EU countries – all of the EMU, or some of its more significant members, or some new EU member states – to test the importance of the credit channel trans-mission of monetary policy;

2.     The adaptation of the Bernanke and Blinder (1988) model with the introduction of four ra-tios to represent the bank-performance condi-tions: bank deposits/GDP; bonds and money market instruments/GDP; foreign assets/GDP; and foreign assets/foreign liabilities;

3.     The use of panel data estimations – pooled panel OLS estimations and dynamic Arellano-Bond




© Cândida Ferreira, 2010.

I kindly thank the pertinent comments and suggestions of the editors of the “Banks and Bank Systems” International Research Journal. They were all taken into account and several sentences and particularly footnotes were inserted in this version of the paper. However, the usual disclaimer applies.



1 More precisely, we use the data for Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Cy-prus, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden and United Kingdom.



230




Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) esti-mations – not only to confirm the importance of the bank lending channel, but also to draw con-clusions on the level of financial integration of the EU countries.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 1 presents the contextual setting and the relevant literature; the methodological framework and the data are presented in Section 2; Section 3 displays the results obtained; finally in the last Sec-tion, we make our concluding remarks.

1. Contextual setting and literature

In recent years and particularly during the last dec-ade, the banking activity has had to adapt to profound transformations, due to advances in information and financial technologies and changes in institutional and regulatory conditions, together with shocks from the socio-economic and financial environment.

In the EU, the structural changes arising first from the adoption of the single currency and a common monetary policy and then from the recent histori-cally remarkable enlargement, which brought the entry of ten countries at the same time, followed shortly after by two more countries, have had a pro-found impact, not only in the Euro area but also throughout the entire EU-27, where the financial sector has experienced an intensification of competi-tion in banking services.

Some authors have already analyzed the degrees of integration through the common trends which may be identified in the context of the pressures of glob-alization and which affect all the EU countries (not only the EMU members) with particular intensity, due to the process of disintermediation, new tech-nologies and increased competition (Belaisch et al., 2001; Gardener et al., 2002; Melnik and Nissim, 2006).

The increasingly competitive environment of the EU banking sector and the process of concentration as well as the decline in the number of banks in almost all EU countries, did not eliminate much of the ex-cess capacity in the system. Moreover, there is evi-dence that large banks continue to have efficiency advantages over the smaller banks (Altunbas et al., 1997; Cabral et al., 2002; Casu and Molyneux, 2000; Jansen and de Haan, 2003; Molyneux, 2003; Baele et al., 2004; Romero-Ávila, 2003 and 2007).

In Barros et al. (2007), the efficiency of almost 1400 commercial banks operating in the EU be-tween 1993 and 2001 was analyzed. The study confirmed the importance of country-level charac-teristics and firm-level features to explain the probability of a bank being a best (worst) per-former. In particular, we concluded that smaller-

Banks and Bank Systems, Volume 5, Issue 2, 2010

sized banks with higher loan intensity and foreign banks from countries upholding common law traditions have a higher probability of best per-formance.

It is generally recognized that nowadays special at-tention must be paid to the EU banking sector follow-ing the most recent enlargements mentioned above, particularly regarding those countries formerly under the Soviet Union sphere of influence, given that in a quite short period of time, the banks in these coun-tries moved from the structure of socialist banking, in which the financial organizations were used to sup-port the central banking system, to a market economy and the concomitant decentralization and liberalization of the banking systems.

In most of these Eastern and Central European coun-tries, forms and programs were introduced to amend property rights, together with processes of privatiza-tions of part of the State property. As a result, the importance of the private sector and firms increased in these countries, as did the particularly relevant role of their financial intermediaries and banking institu-tions. There is a fairly strong consensus on the in-creased performance and efficiency of the banks under the new market conditions in these countries. Several studies (Holscher, 2000; Winkler, 2002; Backhaus, 2003; Sztyber, 2003; Hanousek and Kocenda, 2003; Stephen and Backhaus, 2003; Tchipev, 2003; Dimi-trova, 2004; Bonin and Watchel, 2004; Bonin et al., 2005-a, 2005-b; Freis and Taci, 2005; Fries et al., 2006) confirm the relevant improvements in efficiency of the banking systems of the new EU members and the effects of ownership, concluding that foreign-owned banks are usually more cost-efficient.

Other studies examine how, and to what extent, the banking sectors of the new member-states have in-tegrated with those of the older EU members and the process of nominal and real convergence of these countries to EU standards (ECB, 2004 and 2005; Kocenda et al., 2006).

The transmission of monetary policy to the non-monetary economic sectors also requires more effi-cient banking and the way that banks adapt lending in response to monetary policy decisions varies accord-ing to their specific political and economic environ-ment. However, in spite of all the theoretical and empirical advances in this area, there is still no agreement about the precise specification of the ways in which monetary policy influences the economy. Thus, it is acknowledged as an area meriting further investigation (Goddart et al., 2007).

Some contributions to the explanation of the classic interest-rate channel transmission of monetary policy (Taylor, 1995; Cecchetti, 1995; Bean et al., 2002) imply that the influence of interest rates on economic



231


Banks and Bank Systems, Volume 5, Issue 2, 2010

activity affects, at least, the components of domestic demand. Nowadays, the traditional interest-rate channel is not the only transmission mechanism of monetary policy. Mishkin (1995, 2001) adds an asset-price channel and an exchange-rate channel, sum-ming up the new different mechanisms as “other asset prices” and the “credit view”.

This credit channel may be seen as the development and extension of the conventional interest-rate effect (also developed by Bernanke and Getler, 1995, as well as Hubbard, 1995), taking into account the rising evaluation and monitoring costs for lenders, due to the information asymmetries in credit mar-kets which provoke adverse selection and moral hazard effects.

According to this credit view, monetary policy deci-sions will affect not only the credit demand side, through the balance sheet channel, but also the sup-ply side, through the bank lending channel. More precisely, for instance, the tightening of monetary policy, through the balance sheet channel will make external finance more costly for borrowers with the increase of their interest expenses and the reduction of their collateral while, through the bank lending channel, the reduction of the banks’ liquidity will force banking institutions to reduce lending.

However, such a reduction also reflects the banks’ characteristics and the environment in which banks are operating. Lending by smaller and relatively under-capitalized or illiquid banks is usually more sensitive to interest rate movements (Kashyap and Stein, 1997, 2000; Kishan and Opiela, 2006).

This paper follows the vectors of research that adapt and develop the pioneer Bernanke and Blinder (1988) model, and particularly:

1.     The empirical papers that recently have tested the existence of a bank lending channel for the transmission of monetary policies in the Euro zone, obtaining rather similar conclusions on the relative homogeneity of the behavior of the EU banking institutions (Erhmann et al., 2001; Fountas and Papagapitos, 2001; Topi and Vil-munen, 2001; Van Els et al., 2001; Worms, 2001; Altunbas et al., 2002; Angeloni et al., 2002; Gambacorta, 2004; Gambacorta and Mis-trulli, 2004; Ferreira, 2007).

2.    The other contributions that analyze the trans-mission channels of monetary policy in different EU countries, including the new member-states in Central and Eastern Europe (Golinelli and Rovelli, 2005; Elbourne and de Haan, 2006; Ferreira, 2008).



2. Methodological framework and used data

2.1. The model. The used model is an adaptation of the Bernanke and Blinder (1988) model.

In the money market, we will assume that money equals deposits held at banks by the non-monetary sectors. So, for the demand function, we consider that the nominal deposits held in banks by the pri-vate sector will depend positively on the GDP and negatively on the interest rate on bonds:

Depd    a
0
_ a GDP _ a
i
bonds
,
(1)


1
2




where Depd = deposits, d meaning demand; GDP = Gross Domestic Product; ibonds = interest rate on bonds; a1 > 0; a2 < 0.

On the other side, money supply will depend not only on the interest rate on bonds, but also on the influence of monetary policy (represented here by the relevant monetary policy interest rate, which is defined by the Central Bank):

Deps   b
_b i
bonds
_b i
mon.pol.
,
(2)

0
1
2




where Deps = deposits, s meaning supply; ibonds = interest rate on bonds; imon.pol. = monetary policy interest rate; b1 > 0; b2 < 0.

At the same time, in the credit market, the demand for lending depends positively on the GDP, nega-tively on the interest rate on lending/borrowing and positively on the interest rate on bonds:

Lendd    c
_ c GDP _
c
i
_ c
i   , (3)
0
1
2
lend
3
bonds

where Lendd = bank lending, d meaning demand; GDP = Gross Domestic Product; ilend = interest rate on lending; ibonds = interest rate on bonds; c1 > 0; c2 < 0; c3 > 0.

Assuming the relevance of one or more bank-performance characteristics (Charx) which may exert either positive or negative influences on lending, we define the supply in the money market as depending on the deposits of the private sectors in banks, as well as on the bank characteristics, the interest rate on lending/borrowing and the interest rate on bonds:

Lends   d
0
_d Dep_d Car _d i
_d i   , (4)


1
2
x
3 lend
4 bonds


with Lends = lending, s meaning supply; Dep = bank deposits of the private sector; Carx = bank character-istics (x = 1,..X); ilend = interest rate on lending; ibonds = interest rate on bonds; d1 > 0; d2 may be > 0 or < 0 so d2 = ?; d3 > 0; d4 < 0.

So, clearing the money market – equations (1) and

(2) – we obtain:






232



where f1 > 0; f2 < 0.
Clearing the credit market – equations (3) and (4) – we first obtain the expression of the interest rate on lending:
Banks and Bank Systems, Volume 5, Issue 2, 2010

i

b0 _a0

_

a1
GDP _

b2
i


Lend
_h0 _h2e0 _h3 f0 _ _ _h1 _h2e1 _h3 f1 _GDP_


a2
_b1

a2
_b1

a2 _b1


__h e

bonds








mon. pol
_h f
2
_i
_h Car




















2 2
3

mon. pol
4
x

or


















or

































ibonds
e0
_e1GDP _e2imon. pol ,




(5)
Lend
D0
_D1GDP _D2imon. pol _D3Carx ,   (9)

with e1 > 0; e2 > 0.











where Lend = bank lending; GDP = Gross Domestic

At the same time, if money demand equals money
Product; imon.pol. = monetary policy interest rate; Carx

supply:


















= bank characteristics (x = 1,..X); D1 > 0 if h2 > 0;

d


s
a2b0 _a0b1

a1b1



a2b2
otherwise D1 may be < 0 ; so D1 = ?; D2 > 0 if h2 > 0

Dep
Dep



_


GDP_

imon.pol
and h2 e2 > h3 f2 ; otherwise D2 may be < 0 ; so D2 = ?



a2 _b1

a2 _b1
a2 _b1

or


















; D3 may be > 0 or < 0 so D3 = ?.



















2.2. The data. To build our panel, we use Eurostat

Dep

f0
_ f1GDP _ f2imon. pol ,




(6)






and International Financial Statistics (IFS) quarterly




















data for the period from Q1 1999 to Q3 2006 (31


quarters) and 26 EU countries, amounting to 806 observations. As mentioned previously, Luxembourg has been excluded, as it was not possible to collect all of the necessary data for this country.


i
lends
d0 _c0

_
d1

Dep _
d2

Car _










c2
_d3



c2 _d


c2 _d

x







3

3


_
d4 _c3
i
_

c1
GDP




c2 _d3
c2 _d3






bond









or

ilend   g0 _g1Dep_g2Carx _g3ibond _g4GDP, (7)

with: g1 < 0; g2 may be > 0 or < 0 so g2 = ?; g3 > 0; g4 > 0.

Using this definition of the interest rate on lending, and admitting the credit market equilibrium, we get:

Lend d    Lend s

c2d0 _c0d3
_

c1d3
GDP _













c2 _d3
c2 _d3


_
c2d4 _c3d3
i
_
c2d1
Dep _
c2d2
Car

c2 _d3

c2 _d3


bond


c2 _d3

x


or

Lend  h0 _h1GDP_h2ibond _h3Dep_h4Carx , (8)

Now: h1 > 0; h2 > 0 if c2 d4 < c3 d3 or h2< 0 if c2 d4 > c3 d3 ; so h2 = ?; h3 > 0; h4 may be > 0 or < 0 so h4 = ?.

Remembering the expressions of the interest rate on bonds and deposits – equations (5) and (6)

ibonds
e0
_ e1GDP _ e2imon. pol ,
(5)
Dep
f0
_ f1GDP _ f2imon. pol ,
(6)

and introducing these expressions into the equation (8), we obtain the reduced form of the expression for lending, which is the basis of our estimations:


For the dependent variable (bank lending) we use the natural logarithm of the ratio of the domestic credit provided by the banking institutions to GDP. To explain the growth of this bank lending, we will consider (always in natural logarithms):

i       the real GDP per capita, representing the mac-roeconomic conditions of the different EU countries;

i       the discount rate (end of the period) which is the monetary policy interest rate;

i       the four ratios which represent the bank per-formance conditions, more precisely:

-  the ratio of deposits to GDP, that is, the total deposits in the banking institutions which are important sources of resources for credit lend-ing. For instance, according to the macroeco-nomic money multiplier mechanism, bank lending will mainly depend on the collected deposits and the legal minimum reserves;

-   the ratio of the bonds and money market in-struments to GDP, as a proxy of the develop-ment of the financial markets in these coun-tries, which are mostly bank-dominated. Since healthy financial markets and developed finan-cial institutions are a guarantee for the direct and indirect financing of the bank clients’ ac-tivities, we may expect that this ratio will exert a positive influence on bank lending;

-  the ratio of foreign assets to GDP, introducing the influence of the other countries, more specifically, the financial resources obtained from foreign partners, represented by the en-try of assets, in particular to pay their debts and financial obligations, and consequently, more resources to be applied in the domestic bank lending;



233


Banks and Bank Systems, Volume 5, Issue 2, 2010

-  the ratio of foreign assets to foreign liabilities, representing the financial situation of the bank-ing institutions towards other countries, as they may receive payments from foreign debtors. On the other hand, they also have financial ob-ligations towards foreign creditors, which im-plies the payment of debts and obligations to other countries. Therefore, the influence of this ratio on bank lending will reveal not only the openness of the financial markets, but mainly the degree of dependence on the other coun-tries’ financial resources.

In Appendix A, we present the summary statistics of these series, while the matrix of the correlations is presented in Appendix B.

2.3. Unit root tests. The collected data for 26 EU countries for a time period of 31 quarters (806 obser-vations in total) does not lend itself to the application of single time series unit root tests. Therefore, we opt to use panel unit root tests, which are more adequate in this case (see, among others, Karlsson and Loth-gren, 2000; Wooldridge, 2002; Basile et al., 2005). These tests not only increase the power of unit root tests due to the span of the observations, but also minimize the risks of structural breaks due to possible changes in policy regimes.

Among the available panel unit root tests, we choose the Levin, Lin and Chu (2002) test, which may be viewed as a pooled Dickey-Fuller test or as an aug-mented Dickey-Fuller test when lags are included, and the null hypothesis is the existence of non-stationarity. This test is adequate for heterogeneous panels of moderate size, as is the present case, and it assumes that there is a common unit root process.

According to the results obtained with the determi-nistic constant and trend up to 3 lags (see Appendix C), the existence of the null hypothesis may be re-jected for all the variables, mostly with no lags, except for the monetary policy interest rate when lags are equal to one or two, while for the ratio of bonds and money market instruments to GDP the best results are obtained with three lags.

3. Empirical estimations

Using the reduced form (equation (9)) of the pre-sented model, and the series described above, we will explain the response of bank lending to relevant macroeconomic conditions, as well as to some spe-cific characteristics of the banking institutions and indicators representing their performance condi-tions, by the estimation of the following equation (all variables in natural logarithms1):

(Bank Lending/GDP) it =_M_0 + M 1 real GDP per cap.it + M 2 Interest rate it + M 3 (Deposits/GDP) it +_M 4 (Bonds and Money Market Instruments/GDP) it + M 5 (Foreign Assets/GDP) it + M 6 (Foreign As-sets/Foreign Liabilities) it + Ki + Qt + uit,

where i = 1,..., 26 (EU countries); t = 1,..., 31 (quarters, between Q1 1999 and Q3 2006); Ki = country dum-mies; Qt = time (quarter) dummies; uit = error term.

Therefore, with a panel of 806 observations, we will use a panel data approach which not only provides more observations for estimations, but also reduces the possibility of multi-collinearity among the dif-ferent variables.

To check for the robustness of the results and the relative importance of the macroeconomic, monetary policy and bank performance conditions for the ex-planation of the bank lending growth, we will present the results of three equations: the first including all the explaining variables; the second excluding the real GDP per capita but including all the other five explaining variables (monetary policy interest rate and the four ratios representing bank performance conditions); and the last equation explaining the bank lending growth only by the bank performance con-ditions. In our model these bank performance condi-tions are represented by: the deposits / GDP ratio, the bonds and money market instruments / GDP ratio; the foreign assets / GDP ratio and the foreign assets / foreign liabilities ratio.

For the estimations, we will use:

i       pooled panel ordinary least squares (OLS) robust estimates, following Wooldridge (2002); and

i       dynamic panel Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) estimates, following the methodology developed by Arellano and Bond (1991), Blun-dell and Bond (1998), Windmeijer (2000) and Bond (2002).

3.1. Pooled panel OLS robust estimations. With pooled total, ordinary least squares (OLS) robust estimates, we test the degree of integration assuming a common intercept and a single set of slope coeffi-cients for all the panel observations.

The obtained results for the three presented equations are reported in Table 1 and in all situations reveal consistency. In line with the previously presented unit root tests, the best results were obtained without any lagged variables2, indicating the dynamic and imme-diate reaction of bank lending growth to the real per-capita GDP growth, the monetary policy interest rate and the four bank performance indicators and condi-tions included in our model.



1 Good explanations of the advantages and importance of using loga-rithmic transformation in regression estimates are available, among others in Beauchamp and Olson (1973) or Bartik (1985).



2 The results of the estimations including lagged variables are available from the author upon request.



234




Table 1. Pooled OLS robust estimations (*)


EQUATION I
EQUATION II
EQUATION III






Real GDP per capita





coef.

.3054466




T-statistic

2.73




P-value

0.006




Interest rate





coef.

.108883
.0944373



T-statistic

3.28
2.77



P-value

0.001
0.006



Deposits/GDP





coef.

.1937137
.2126949
.1918622


T-statistic

3.84
4.16
3.77


P-value

0.000
0.000
0.000


Bonds and money market instruments / GDP



coef.

.1401866
.1427856
.159362


T-statistic

6.78
7.02
8.20


P-value

0.000
0.000
0.000


Foreign assets / GDP





coef.

.1706834
.1625786
.1774548


T-statistic

4.45
4.40
4.92


P-value

0.000
0.000
0.000


Foreign assets / Foreign liabilities




coef.

-.135372
-.1475844
-.1393685


T-statistic

-5.44
-6.11
-5.68


P-value

0.000
0.000
0.000


constant





coef.

-.5142468
.8122658
.97971


T-statistic

-1.10
5.93
9.23


P-value

0.270
0.000
0.000











N = 806
N = 806
N = 806




F (61, 744) =
F (60, 745) =
F (59, 746) =




1119.72
1226.02
1237.57




Prob > F =
Prob > F =
Prob > F =




0.0000
0.0000
0.0000




R-squared =
R-squared =
R-squared =




0.9773
0.9769
0.9766



Notes: (*) Time and country dummies were included in the estimations and the obtained results are available upon request.

According to the results presented in Table 1, the three models are statistically acceptable, as not only the values of the R-squares and the F-statistics are very high but also the t-statistics and the correspondent p-values of all variables are quite significant.

In all situations, only the ratio of foreign assets to foreign liabilities has a negative influence on the bank lending growth, confirming the high degree of foreign dependence and indebtedness of the EU financial systems during this period.

All the other explanatory variables contribute posi-tively to bank lending growth. In addition, the relative high influence of the ratio of the bonds and money market instruments to GDP confirms that the EU finan-cial and credit systems continue to be bank-dominated, since the increase of the bonds and money market in-struments are in line with the bank lending growth.

Banks and Bank Systems, Volume 5, Issue 2, 2010

The positive contribution of the monetary policy interest rate to bank lending is not a surprise, in view of the fact that during this period, the ECB in particular, as well as the central banks of the non-EMU member-states, maintained interest rates at historically low levels, thereby contributing to the growth of the ratio bank lending to GDP.

3.2. Arellano-Bond dynamic panel GMM estima-tions. In addition, we present the results obtained with dynamic Arellano-Bond panel GMM estimates (two-step difference), which consider the model as a system of equations, one for each time period. The equations differ by their individual moment condi-tion sets, since they all include the endogenous and exogenous variables in first differences as instru-ments with suitable lags of their own levels. By this use of instruments based on lagged values of the explanatory variables, GMM controls for the poten-tial endogeneity of all explanatory variables, al-though only for “weak” endogeneity and not for full endogeneity, as explained by Bond (2002).

Next, we check for the quality of the estimations by the Hansen test for over-identifying restrictions and the Arellano-Bond tests for autocorrelation.

Table 2. Arellano-Bond dynamic panel GMM two-step difference estimations


EQUATION I
EQUATION II
EQUATION III





Real GDP per capita





coef.
-.1541594




z
-6.01




P>|z|
0.000




Interest rate (lag1)





coef.
.0530916
.0512398



z
4.97
4.30



P>|z|
0.000
0.000



Deposits/GDP





coef.
.4676554
.4839136
.5198482


z
22.21
18.63
20.54


P>|z|
0.000
0.000
0.000


Bonds and money market instruments/GDP (lag3)



coef.
.2189317
.1646729
.0797324


z
8.16
8.69
4.13


P>|z|
0.000
0.000
0.000


Foreign assets/GDP





coef.
.0611868
.0809159
.086716


z
3.87
4.90
8.26


P>|z|
0.000
0.000
0.000


Foreign assets/Foreign liabilities




coef.
-.1879588
-.1997773
-.1983791


z
-8.67
-10.83
-25.70


P>|z|
0.000
0.008
0.000









N = 702
N = 702
N = 702


Hansen test of
chi2(129) = 21.30
chi2 (130) =
chi2 (131) =


24.46
22.67


Prob > chi2 =


overid. restrictions:
Prob > chi2 =
Prob > chi2 =


1.000



1.000
1.000









235


Banks and Bank Systems, Volume 5, Issue 2, 2010

Table 2. Arellano-Bond dynamic panel GMM two-step difference estimations

EQUATION I
EQUATION II
EQUATION III





Arellano-Bond test
z = -1.88
z = -2.30
z = -1.93


for AR(1) in first


Pr > z = 0.060
Pr > z = 0.022
Pr > z = 0.053


differences:







Arellano-Bond test
z = -0.36
z = -0.67
z = -0.75


for AR(2) in first


Pr > z = 0.719
Pr > z = 0.501
Pr > z = 0.456


differences:








Table 2 reports the obtained results with dynamic Arellano-Bond two-step difference GMM estima-tions for the three presented equations. Now, rein-forcing the conclusions of the presented unit root tests, the best results in statistical terms are obtained with lagged values, but only for the monetary policy interest rate and for the ratio of bonds and money market instruments to GDP.

In all situations, the Hansen test1 clearly does not reject the null that the instruments are valid and that they are not correlated with the errors. At the same time, according to the results of the Arellano-Bond tests, and as required for the validity of the instru-ments, we may always accept that the residuals are clearly MA (1), but not MA (2).

Furthermore, except for the growth of the real GDP per capita2 (included only in equation (1), all the results obtained with Arellano-Bond dynamic GMM estimates are in line with those obtained with the pooled panel OLS estimates.

With regard to real growth of the GDP per capita, we know that while it may be possible to admit a positive relation between real GDP growth and bank lending growth, it may also be true that during at least some of the considered time periods, bank lending was not so directly connected with the pro-ductive activities. This may be due either to the relatively independent and more productive financ-ing of the productive activities, or to the channelling of credit towards less productive activities, such as home buying or private consumption, with no re-markable future productive multiplier effects.

Concluding remarks

This paper confirms the high degree of integration among the EU financial systems, as well as the im-portance of bank performance conditions to the credit-lending channel of monetary policy in the EU countries during recent years.

1 The Hansen test is a test of over-identifying restrictions. The null hy-pothesis for this test is that the instruments are valid in the sense that they are not correlated with the errors in the first-differenced equation. Under the null, this test statistic has a F_2q distribution with q equal to the total number of instruments minus the number of parameters in the model.

2 To check the robustness of these results, we estimate several equations with and without lags and in all situations with Arellano-Bond GMM estimates (two-step difference), the real GDP per capita has a negative influence on the bank lending to GDP. The results are available upon request.



We contribute to the existing empirical evidence by the introduction into an adaptation of the Bernanke and Blinder (1988) model not only of the real GDP per capita or the monetary policy interest rate, but also of some specific variables, representing the bank performance conditions, to explain bank lend-ing to GDP, namely, the bank deposits / GDP ratio; the bonds and money market instruments / GDP ratio, the foreign assets / GDP ratio and the foreign assets / foreign liabilities ratio.

The consistency of the obtained results, using pooled OLS and dynamic Arellano-Bond GMM panel estimations, allows us to conclude that the EU banking institutions have similar reactions to the variations of the macroeconomic conditions, in par-ticular to the monetary policy interest rates as well as to the variations of the bank performance condi-tions. The results also confirm the importance of these variables to the bank lending growth (more precisely, the growth of the ratio of the domestic credit provided by the banking institutions to GDP) in the EU countries.

With reference to the real GDP per capita, the ob-tained results, although statistically robust, are in-conclusive as to the positive or negative influence of this variable on the bank lending to GDP growth during this period. With OLS robust estimates, which consider a fully integrated panel, with com-mon intercept and a single set of slope coefficients, we conclude that a faster growth of the real GDP per capita will contribute to a faster growth of the bank lending to GDP growth. However, when using Arellano-Bond GMM estimations, which consider the model as a system of equations, one for each time period, we found a negative influence of the real GDP per capita growth to bank lending growth.

Thus, we may conclude that, in at least some of the considered time periods, bank lending was not posi-tively related to the real GDP per capita growth. This may be true in some EU countries, where the historically low levels of interest rates oriented bank credit to many non-productive activities3. These results are corroborated with the clear positive con-tributions of the monetary policy interest rate to bank lending growth.

Furthermore, the results obtained with the four in-cluded bank performance conditions allow us to state that:


3 Since we are using panel data estimates we can not identify exactly the countries where bank lending growth is more negatively correlated with GDP growth. Nevertheless, it is well known that more efficient and well developed banking institutions should contribute to a more productive use of bank lending and that during the considered time period the EU coun-tries and their banking institutions were still adapting to the new market and credit conditions and particularly to the intensification of competition.



236


Banks and Bank Systems, Volume 5, Issue 2, 2010



1.    the growth of the ratio of deposits to GDP exerts a positive influence on the bank lending growth, confirming the intermediate role of financial in-stitutions and the fact that the capacity to attract savings (in the form of deposits) is always a good condition in which to provide credit to those who need financing;

2.     the growth of the ratio of bonds and money mar-ket instruments to GDP, which can be considered as a proxy of the development of the financial markets in the EU countries, also contributes positively to bank lending. This is symptomatic not only of the fact that the EU financial markets continue to be bank-dominated, but also that the development of the financial systems is always a good condition for the direct and indirect financ-ing of the bank clients’ activities;

3.    as expected, the growth of the ratio of foreign assets to GDP also exerts a positive influence on the bank lending growth, as the entry of foreign assets received from the other countries in-creases the resources to concede credit to the domestic banks’ clients;

References


4.     the growth of the ratio of foreign assets to for-eign liabilities contributes negatively to the do-mestic bank lending growth, revealing not only the openness of the financial markets, but more importantly, their indebtedness and the depend-ence of the EU banking institutions on other countries’ financial resources.

Finally, it is clear that the total credit provided by the UE banking institutions depends on the macro-economic conditions, and particularly on the mone-tary policy decisions. At the same time, bank lend-ing is an essential transmission channel of mone-tary policy decisions, but it still depends on the performance conditions of the different financial institutions.

Taking into account the lessons of the recent banking and financial crisis, future research in this area will have to underline the relevance of more efficient banking sectors and their specific role in the transmission mechanisms of monetary policy.



1.     Angeloni, I., A. Kashyap, B. Mojon and D. Terlizzese (2002), Monetary Transmission in the Euro Zone: Where do we Stand?, ECB Working Paper Nº 114, January.

2.     Altunbas, Y., Ph. Molyneux and J. Thornton (1997), "Big-Bank Mergers in Europe: An Analysis of the Cost Im-plications", Economica, London School of Economics and Political Science, 64 (254), pp. 317-329.

3.     Altunbas, Y., O. Fazylow and Ph. Molyneux (2002), "Evidence on the bank lending channel in Europe", Journal of Banking and Finance, 26 (11), pp. 2093-2110.

4.     Arellano, M. and S. Bond (1991), “Some tests of specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo evidence and an appli-cation to employment equations”, The Review of Economic Studies, No. 58, pp. 277-297.
5.     Backhaus, J.G. (2003), “Mass privatization in Central and East European countries: Implications for corporate governance”, Journal of Economic Studies, 30 (3-4), pp. 196-204.
6.     Baele, L., A. Ferrando, P. Hordahl, E. Krylova and C. Monnet (2004), Measuring banking integration in the Euro area, ECB Occasional Paper No. 14.

7.     Barros, C.P., C. Ferreira and J. Williams (2007), “Analysing the determinants of performance of best and worse European banks: A mixed logit approach”, Journal of Banking and Finance, 31 (7), pp. 2189-2203.
8.     Bartik, T. (1985), “Business Location Decisions in the United States: Estimates of the Effects of Unionization, Taxes and Other Characteristics of States”, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 3 (1) pp. 14-22.

9.     Basile, R., M. Constantini and S. Destefanis (2005), Unit Root and co-integration tests for cross-sectional corre-lated panels. Estimation Regional production functions, CELPE, CSEF Università di Salerno Discussion Paper 94.

10.  Bean, C., J. Larsen and K. Nikolov (2002), Financial Frictions and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism: The-ory, Evidence and Policy Implications, ECB Working Paper Nº 113, January.

11.  Beauchamp, J. and J. Olson (1973), “Corrections for Bias in Regression Estimates After Logarithmic Transforma-tion”, Ecology, 54 (6), pp. 1403-1407.

12.  Belaisch, A., L. Kodres, J. Levy and A. Ubide (2001), Euro-Area Banking at the Crossroads, IMF Working Paper No 01/28 Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund.

13.  Bernanke, B. and A. Blinder (1988), "Credit, Money and Aggregate Demand", American Economic Review, No. 78 (2), pp. 435-439.

14.   Bernanke, B. and M. Gertler (1995), "Inside the Black Box: the credit channel transmission of monetary policy",

Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9 (4), pp. 27-48.

15.  Blundell, R. and S. Bond (1998), “Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models”, Jour-nal of Econometrics, No. 87, p. 115-143.
16.  Bond, S. (2002), Dynamic panel data models: A guide to micro data methods and practice, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London, Working Paper No. 09/02.

17.   Bonin, J. and P. Watchel (2004), “Dealing with Financial Fragility in Transition Economies”, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Conference on “Systemic Financial Crises: Resolving Large Bank Insolvencies”, September 30.

18.  Bonin, J., I. Hasan and P. Watchel (2005-a), “Bank performance efficiency and ownership in transition econo-mies”, Journal of Banking and Finance, 29 (1), pp. 31-53.



237


Banks and Bank Systems, Volume 5, Issue 2, 2010

19.  Bonin, J., I. Hasan and P. Watchel (2005-b), “Privatization matters: Bank efficiency in transition economies”,

Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 29 (8-9), pp. 2155-2178.

20.   Cabral, I., F. Dierick and J. Vesala (2002), Banking integration in the Euro area, ECB Occasional Paper No. 6.

21.   Casu, B. and Ph. Molyneux. (2000), A Comparative Study of Efficiency in European Banking, Centre for Financial Institutions Working Papers No 00-17, Wharton School Centre for Financial Institutions, University of Pennsylvania.

22.  Cecchetti, S. (1995), "Distinguishing Theories of the Monetary Transmission Mechanism", FRB of St. Louis Eco-nomic Review, 77, pp. 83-97.
23.  Dimitrova, A. ed. (2004), Driven to Change: The European Union’s Enlargement views from the East, Manchester University Press.

24.   Elbourne, A. and J. de Hann (2006), Financial structure and monetary policy transmission in transition countries,

Journal of Comparative Economics, 34 (1), pp. 1-23.

25.  Erhmann, M., L. Gambacorta,, J. Martinez-Pagés,, P. Sevestre and A. Worms (2001), Financial Systems and the Role of Banks in Monetary Policy Transmission in the Euro Zone, ECB Working Paper Nº 105.

26.  European Central Bank (2004), Research network on capital markets and financial integration in Europe – Research and experience after two years, The Joint ECB-CFS Research Network, December.
27.  European Central Bank (2005), Banking Structures in the New EU Member States, ECB, January.

28.   Ferreira, C. (2007), “Interest Rates, Banking Institutions and Transmission of Monetary Policy in the Euro-Zone – Some empirical results for Portugal during the last decade”, European Journal of Finance, 13 (1-2), pp. 181-193.

29.  Ferreira, C. (2008), “The Banking Sector, Economic Growth and European Integration”, Journal of Economic Studies, forthcoming.
30.  Fountas, S. and A. Papagapitos (2001), “The monetary transmission mechanism: evidence and implications for European Monetary Union”, Economics Letters, 70, pp. 397-404.
31.  Fries, S. and A. Taci (2005), “Cost efficiency of banks in transition: Evidence from 289 in 15 post-communist countries”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 29 (1), pp. 55-81.
32.  Fries, S., D. Neven, P. Seabrigh and A. Taci (2006), “Market entry, privatization and bank performance in transi-tion”, Economics of Transition, Vol. 14 (4), pp. 579-610.
33.   Gambacorta, L. (2004), “Inside the bank lending channel”, European Economic Review, 49 (7), pp. 1737-1759.

34.  Gambacorta, L. and Mistrulli, P.E. (2004), “Does bank capital affect lending behavior?”, Journal of Financial Intermediation, Nº 13, pp. 436-457.
35.  Gardener, E., Ph. Molyneux, Ph. and B. Moore (ed.) (2002), Banking in the New Europe – The Impact of the Sin-gle Market Program and EMU on the European Banking Sector, Palgrave, Macmillan.

36.  Goddart, J., Ph. Molyneux, J.O.S. Wilson and M. Tavakoli (2007), “European Banking: An overview”, Journal of Banking and Finance, 31 (7), pp. 1911-1935.

37.  Golinelli, R. and R. Rovelli (2005), Monetary policy transmission, interest rate rules and inflation targeting in three transition countries, Journal of Banking and Finance, 29 (1), pp. 183-201.
38.  Gujarati D. (2003), Basic Econometrics, McGraw-Hill. Boston
39.  Hanousek, J. and E. Kocenda (2003), “The impact of Czech mass privatisation on corporate governance”, Journal of Economic Studies, 30 (3-4), pp. 278-293.
40.  Holscher, J. ed. (2000), Financial Turbulence and Capital Markets in Transition Countries, Palgrave editions.
41.  Hubbard, R.G. (1995), “Is there a credit channel for monetary policy?”, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 77 (3), pp. 63-77.

42.  Jansen, D-J. and J. de Haan (2003), Increasing concentration in European banking: a macro-level analysis WO No. 743, Netherlands Central Bank, Research Department.
43.  Karlsson, S. And M. Lothgren (2000), “On the power and interpretation of panel unit root tests”, Economics Let-ters, 66 (3), pp. 249-255.

44.  Kashyap, A.K. and J. C. Stein (1997), “The role of banks in monetary policy: A survey with implication for the European Monetary Union”, Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 21, pp. 2-19.

45.  Kashyap, A.K. and J.C. Stein (2000), “What do a million banks have to say about the transmission of monetary policy”, American Economic Review, 90, pp. 407-428.
46.  Kishan, R.P. and T.P. Opiela (2006), “Bank capital and loan asymetry in the transmission of monetary policy”,
Journal of Banking and Finance, 30 (1), pp. 259-285.

47.  Kocenda, E., A.M. Kutan and T.M. Yigit (2006), "Pilgrims to the Eurozone: How Far, How Fast?" Economic Systems, 30 (4), pp. 311-327.
48.   Levin, A., C. Lin and C. Chu (2002), “Unit Root Tests in Panel Data: Asymptotic and Finite Sample Properties”,

Journal of Econometrics, No. 108, pp.1-24.

49.  Melnik, A. and D. Nissim (2006), “Issue costs in the Eurobond market: The effects of market integration”, Journal of Banking and Finance, 30 (1), pp. 157-177.
50.  Mishkin, F. (1995), “Symposium on the monetary transmission mechanisms”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9 (4), pp. 3-10.

51.  Mishkin, F. (2001), The Economics of Money, Banking and Financial Markets, Sixth Edition, Addison Wesley, World Student Series.

52.  Molyneux, Ph. (2003), “Does Size Matter?” – Financial Restructuring under EMU EIFC - Technology and Fi-nance Working Papers 30, United Nations University, Institute for New Technologies.



238


Banks and Bank Systems, Volume 5, Issue 2, 2010

53.  Romero-Ávila, D. (2003), Finance and growth in the EU: New evidence from the liberalisation and harmonisation of the banking industry, ECB Working Paper, No. 266.

54.  Romero-Ávila, D. (2007), “Finance and growth in the EU: New evidence from the harmonisation of the banking industry”, Journal of Banking and Finance 31 (7), pp. 1937-1954.

55.   Stephen F.H. and J.G. Backhaus (2003), “Corporate governance and mass privatisation: A theoretical investigation and transformations in legal and economic relationships”, Journal of Economic Studies, 30 (3-4), pp. 389-468.

56.  Sztyber, W. (2003), “Polish mass privatisation scheme: The programme of national investment funds”, Journal of Economic Studies, 30 (3-4), pp. 205-228.
57.  Taylor, J. (1995), "The Monetary Transmission Mechanism: An Empirical Framework", Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9, pp.11-26.
58.  Tchipev, P. (2003), “Bulgarian mass privatisation scheme: Implications on corporate governance”, Journal of Economic Studies, 30, (3-4), pp. 351-388.
59.  Topi, J. and J. Vilmunen (2001), Transmission of Monetary Policy Shocks in Finland: Evidence from Bank Level Data on Loans, ECB Working Paper No. 73, July.

60.  Van Els, P., A Locarno, J. Morgan and J-P Villetelle (2001), Monetary Policy Transmission in The Euro Zone: What Do Aggregate and National Structural Models Tell Us?, ECB Working Paper NO 94, December.

61.  Windmeijer, F. (2000), A finite simple correction for the variance of linear two-step GMM estimators, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London, Working Paper No 00/19.

62.   Winkler, A. ed. (2002), Banking and Monetary Policy in the Eastern Europe: the First Ten Years, Palgrave editions.

63.  Wooldridge, J. (2002), Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, the MIT Press.

64.   Worms, A. (2001), The Reaction of Bank Lending to Monetary Policy, ECB Working Paper No. 96, December.

Appendix A. Summary statistics
VARIABLES
Mean
Std. dev.
Min
Max
Observations




(all in natural logarithms)









Bank lending/GDP:







overall
.9634144
1.106034
-3.23828
3.39354
N = 806


between

1.10247
-2.791806
3.356673
n = 26


within

.2305816
.0820338
3.117834
T = 31


Real GDP per capita:







overall
6.051168
2.678176
1.34968
12.66796
N = 806


between

2.72726
1.443205
12.42524
n = 26


within

.1089511
5.524108
6.514988
T = 31


Interest rate:







overall
1.481935
.56964
-.02703
3.55535
N = 806


between

.4792346
.7142648
3.06961
n = 26


within

.3215321
.4369553
2.581846
T = 31


Deposits/GDP:







overall
1.295129
1.519575
-2.77394
6.04847
N = 806


between

1.528612
-2.488646
5.997196
n = 26


within

.2439945
-.3845842
1.981864
T = 31


Bonds and money market instruments/GDP:







overall
-.0795288
1.750138
-5.39641
2.28638
N = 806


between

1.695878
-3.744695
1.986973
n = 26


within

.5423645
-2.622679
1.495851
T = 31


Foreign assets/GDP :







overall
-.080594
2.21202
-10.41371
3.23734
N = 806


between

2.240099
-9.21917
2.771957
n = 26


within

.2489938
-1.275133
.6851366
T = 31


Foreign assets/Foreign liabilities :







overall
-.0051242
.7618599
-2.47735
2.88475
N = 806


between

.6818787
-1.203865
2.336299
n = 26


within

.3644169
-1.446609
2.090331
T = 31



Appendix B. Correlation matrix (*)


Real lending/
Real GDP
Interest rate
Deposits/
Bonds and money
Foreign as-
Foreign as-






market instruments/
sets/Foreign



GDP
per capita
GDP
sets/GDP




GDP
liabilities










Bank lending/GDP
1.0000








Real GDP per capita
-0.1951
1.0000










239


Banks and Bank Systems, Volume 5, Issue 2, 2010

Appendix B (cont). Correlation matrix (*)


Real lending/
Real GDP
Interest rate
Deposits/
Bonds and money
Foreign as-
Foreign as-


market instruments/
sets/Foreign


GDP
per capita
GDP
sets/GDP



GDP
liabilities








Interest rate
-0.4227
0.1853
1.0000





Deposits/GDP
0.7154
-0.1843
-0.3777
1.0000




Bonds and money market instru-
0.4828
-0.4132
-0.3314
0.4144
1.0000



ments/GDP











Foreign assets/GDP
0.8005
-0.2019
-0.5605
0.6140
0.5878
1.0000


Foreign assets/Foreign liabilities
0.2235
-0.1555
-0.2109
0.4341
0.1835
0.3939
1.0000


Notes: (*) Several of these correlations seem rather high and, in order to reduce the multicollinearity problems, we could have tried an orthogonalization test, but, following among others, Gujarati (2003) these correlations can be considered in an acceptable range.

Appendix C. Panel unit root tests – Levin-Lin-Chu

VARIABLES
Lags
Coefficients
T-value
T-stat.
P>t
N
Bank lending / GDP
0
-0.85254
-48.179
-43.23521
0.0000
750

1
-0.50974
-15.206
2.11907
0.9830
725

2
-0.40864
-10.955
9.39903
1.0000
700

3
-0.38976
-11.328
10.91595
1.0000
675
Real GDP per capita
0
-1.01649
-28.060
-18.99302
0.0000
750

1
-1.57624
-38.559
-26.68914
0.0000
725

2
-1.89295
-26.221
-7.30147
0.0000
700

3
-0.37484
-8.712
25.39089
1.0000
675
Interest rate
0
-0.16644
-8.404
0.48152
0.6849
750

1
-0.22246
-14.416
-5.64454
0.0000
725

2
-0.26835
-15.240
-5.20633
0.0000
700

3
-0.29185
-13.809
-1.49730
0.0672
675
Deposits / GDP
0
-0.40334
-13.622
-5.38483
0.0000
750

1
-0.38278
-11.697
-2.25471
0.0121
725

2
-0.30752
-9.013
1.43541
0.9244
700

3
-0.24927
-7.173
4.77273
1.0000
675
Bonds and money market instruments /
0
-0.20377
-8.980
-0.24074
0.4049
750
GDP







1
-0.22969
-9.423
-0.19688
0.4220
725

2
-0.20166
-7.782
2.50132
0.9938
700

3
-0.34266
-12.507
-2.97402
0.0015
675
Foreign assets / GDP
0
-0.29999
-11.244
-2.56597
0.0051
750

1
-0.29557
-10.280
-0.78186
0.2171
725

2
-0.28142
-8.924
1.69569
0.9550
700

3
-0.31657
-9.217
2.43607
0.9926
675
Foreign assets / Foreign liabilities
0
-0.17329
-9.362
-1.78288
0.0373
750

1
-0.19161
-9.696
-1.77454
0.0380
725

2
-0.20652
-9.886
-1.47377
0.0703
700

3
-0.25318
-11.463
-2.60665
0.0046
675






















240